Mireism: Difference between revisions
(Extended) |
No edit summary |
||
Line 4: | Line 4: | ||
Mireism has been formulated as a political and economic philosophy by the Sokokan stateswoman [[Chika Mirei]]. During her lifetime, she developed the philosphy while applying it to the federal government of the expanding post-colonial nation of Sokoku. As such, the philosophy is based on the political system that gradually developed in Sokoku. This in contrast to most other political philosophies that were formulated as a theory before getting applied in state government. | Mireism has been formulated as a political and economic philosophy by the Sokokan stateswoman [[Chika Mirei]]. During her lifetime, she developed the philosphy while applying it to the federal government of the expanding post-colonial nation of Sokoku. As such, the philosophy is based on the political system that gradually developed in Sokoku. This in contrast to most other political philosophies that were formulated as a theory before getting applied in state government. | ||
There is no single, definitive publication formulating the exact principles of Mireism, but a gathering of scientific publications by Chika Mirei published between 7606 and 7660. The main works include two versions of the Constitution of Sokoku from 7609 and 7643, as well as a more extensive theoretical publication "The justification of the state" from 7654. | There is no single, definitive publication formulating the exact principles of Mireism, but a gathering of scientific publications by Chika Mirei published between 7606 and 7660. The main works also include two versions of the Constitution of Sokoku from 7609 and 7643, as well as a more extensive theoretical publication "The justification of the state" from 7654. | ||
During her lifetime, the philosophy was usually called ''pembenaran'' or ''seitouka'', in Hallisian often refered to as "the pembenaran state". | During her lifetime, the philosophy was usually called ''pembenaran'' or ''seitouka'', in Hallisian often refered to as "the pembenaran state". The term "Mireists" as followers of Chika Mirei's philosophy was applied to a more informal group of parlementarians preparing the 7643 Constitution of Sokoku. Other factions included Chinenists and Satoists, but with the new constitution Mireism became the dominant ideology. But it was only after her death in 7666 that Mireism as a term was starting to get used for Sokoku's structure of federal and state government as a philosophy that could be applied outside Sokoku as well. | ||
==Basic philosophy== | ==Basic philosophy== | ||
Mireism combines elements of Socialism, Orderism, free market capitalism, traditional non-aristocratic government of the region and even Orkanan society and economics. | Mireism combines elements of [[Socialism]], [[Orderism]], free market capitalism, traditional non-aristocratic government of the region and even [[Orkanan]] society and economics. | ||
==== Human interests at the center ==== | ==== Human interests at the center ==== | ||
Line 33: | Line 33: | ||
==== Application in Sokoku ==== | ==== Application in Sokoku ==== | ||
Adult members of an extended family have voting rights on all matters of the family, including economic enterprise and the allocation of common (joint) funds. The head of the extended family or guild or a deputy represents the unit's interest in the local territorial government. At this level, all tax payers within the extended family have a right to vote for city or county representatives and budget allocation. This part of societal and government structure shows a lot of parallells with traditional Orkanan government, especially in the Mellanhand tradition. | Adult members of an extended family have voting rights on all matters of the family, including economic enterprise and the allocation of common (joint) funds. The head of the extended family or guild or a deputy represents the unit's interest in the local territorial government. At this level, all tax payers within the extended family have a right to vote for city or county representatives and budget allocation. This part of societal and government structure shows a lot of parallells with traditional Orkanan government, especially in the [[Mellanhand Orkanan|Mellanhand]] tradition. | ||
The political culture of Sokoku is therefore extremely bottom-up, where the emphasis lies on local self determination and cooperative involvement (organizational self management). This is combined with a more meritocratic approach for public office. Local clans, co-ops and extended families elect representatives into local government, where the local executives then elect regional representation. Through these indirect elections, the level of representative democracy becomes less and less the higher up in the hierarchy of public office. There are no political parties actively represented in any office. | |||
The federal parliament forms the legislative. It has 147 members, of which 144 are appointed through indirect elections in districts roughly the same size in population. Parliament works in 12 general committees, one for each executive Secretariat, with 8-16 members each. Parliament is also organised into 12 regional groups, which function as parliamentary factions. Within these groups, information from the committees is shared in order to prepare for upcoming voting procedures. Usually a regional group votes unanimously as one bloc, but this is not a requirement. For the smaller states, there is only one regional group gathering their representation. But large states like [[Shuuen]] and [[Nelyasyat and Ayatawantin|Nelyasyat & Ayawantin]] have more groups, which leads to some sort of political culture between the regional groups. Some are more progressive, some more traditional, but the groups from smaller states are mixed and vote according to regional interests. | |||
Each state appoints one member into the Federal Council (apart from Nelyasyat and Ayatawantin who can appoint two council members) that forms the backbone of the executive cabinet. Each secretary-general is heading a Federal Secretariat, of which there are 16 at the moment. | |||
== Society == | == Society == | ||
Line 49: | Line 49: | ||
== Economy == | == Economy == | ||
According to [[Chika Mirei]] there is no real difference between an energy based currency and a fiat based one, since both can be expressed as functions of each others: a certain amount of valuable material can be exchanged for a certain amount of energy, and vice versa, through any rather arbitrary exchange rate. A resulting difference is the definition of wealth in Mireism, which isn't based on economic value but on social ones, more akin welfare. Where Orderism sees societal progress in the form of arts and culture as a symptom of a healthy communal system on an energy based economic system, Mireism sees it the opposite way: that a thriving economy is nothing more than a tool to support social progress, where culture, arts and music are the main expressions of individuals and local communities. | |||
Land ownership comes with a license to use the land for economic purposes like agriculture, forestry or building. However, so-called mobile or hidden assets like streaming water or sub-surface resources are jointly owned. Water management and raw material extraction are public domain and as such contolted completely by the government. While the land owners have the first rights to excavate resources, they are only compensated for the work and possible loss of surface land use. But the revenues of the extracted material are the government's, who allocate it through a tender system. | |||
For example, ercinite ore is extracted against a compensation, then it's allocated to an aluminium manufacturer providing the best price for processing the material within the social and ecological requirements set in the tender. The aluminium is then leased through tenders to manufacturers and end users. Buying an aluminium product gives you the right to use it as intended, but the aluminium itself still is owned by the (federal)cstate. At the end of the life cycle, the product can be returned for a deposit, after which the raw material is allocated a next time. Non-renewable resources can be privately owned, but in practical terms there is a tradition of downcycling where those resources are seen as raw material and not as waste. | |||
== Criticism == | |||
According to many political scientists, Mireism is more a political system applied in one single nation and not so much a political philosophy or ideology. According to these criticasters, it is only applicable in Sokoku and has no universal value. This is however a minority stance. | |||
Other analysts see Mireism only as a variation of Orderism and not so much an independent ideology. According to them, Mireism is simply post-colonial Orderism with a monetary system instead of energy accounting. Mireism also suffers from the same disadvantages as Orderism, like nepotism in appointments, authoritarian tendencies and economic inefficiency; albeit to a lesser extent. | |||
The implementation of Mireism in Sokoku has led to almost parallel pillars of powers, where each region has its own hierarchy in public office. Instead of a single field of nepotism, it is spread out among the regional pillars through the federal structure of the nation state. However, nine fields of nepotism is a lot less nepotist than the single field of nepotism around in most Orderist systems. | |||
[[Category:Ideologies]] | [[Category:Ideologies]] |
Revision as of 02:31, 31 May 2024
Mireism is the political system of Sokoku, as well as the political and economic philosophy as formulated by the stateswoman Chika Mirei. It characterised by elements of a planned economy and strong anti-colonial and anti-mercantilist stance. As a political system, Mireism has been limited to Sokoku, but as an ideology it has been influential in many post-colonial nations rejecting a free market capitalist or orderist system.
History
Mireism has been formulated as a political and economic philosophy by the Sokokan stateswoman Chika Mirei. During her lifetime, she developed the philosphy while applying it to the federal government of the expanding post-colonial nation of Sokoku. As such, the philosophy is based on the political system that gradually developed in Sokoku. This in contrast to most other political philosophies that were formulated as a theory before getting applied in state government.
There is no single, definitive publication formulating the exact principles of Mireism, but a gathering of scientific publications by Chika Mirei published between 7606 and 7660. The main works also include two versions of the Constitution of Sokoku from 7609 and 7643, as well as a more extensive theoretical publication "The justification of the state" from 7654.
During her lifetime, the philosophy was usually called pembenaran or seitouka, in Hallisian often refered to as "the pembenaran state". The term "Mireists" as followers of Chika Mirei's philosophy was applied to a more informal group of parlementarians preparing the 7643 Constitution of Sokoku. Other factions included Chinenists and Satoists, but with the new constitution Mireism became the dominant ideology. But it was only after her death in 7666 that Mireism as a term was starting to get used for Sokoku's structure of federal and state government as a philosophy that could be applied outside Sokoku as well.
Basic philosophy
Mireism combines elements of Socialism, Orderism, free market capitalism, traditional non-aristocratic government of the region and even Orkanan society and economics.
Human interests at the center
The philosophy has been labelled "true socialism" as well, since it puts social values and the human scale central in its tenets. This opposed to many other political philosophies that are based on the way the economy is functioning. According to Chika Mirei, economy is a tool and not a goal. She has even called free market economy a "self fulfilling prophecy" and Orderist economy "a technocratic religion with energy as its new deity".
Mireism includes bottom-up elements like the extended family as a basis for society with economic and individual freedom. At a local level, participative and representative democracy are commonplace. This aspect has been imported from Orkanan style of government, but was present in the more tribal structures of many native populations even before colonial times, where the extended family or village tribe were the main element in society. A lot of decision making that affects social life of the community and the individual can and should be made at a very local level, where the individual should be included in the process.
Ecological boundaries
Beside the social sustainability, where society should not over.ask the capacity of the community and individuals, an important aspect of Mireism are the ecological boundaries. Society as a whole can not survive if the ecosystem of which it is a part is slowly degrading. This applies to factors as raw material and energy but also soil resource supplies and biodiversity. Society should contribute to vital ecosystems, not develop at the cost of it.
Mireist government
Since the ideology started as an anti-colonial philosophy, Chika Mirei put a lot of effort in defining the role of the nation state and its government when it comes to social and ecological aspects. Here she took inspiration from the Tsuki Integrality, where the domination on a single but vital aspect of social and economic life - in this case trade and the transportation of goods - was enough to build an interlinked and common government at a very limited scale, resulting in large regional and individual freedom. Mireism abandoned the idea of a large government planning all aspects of life, like Socialism and Orderism tend to do.
The role of the state thus is the allocation of resources for the benefit of the many. This is where the social and ecological aspects overlap and can be influenced by government intervention. Resources as formulated by Chika Mirei can be in the form of raw material, financing or intellectual property; the latter mainly through state owned patents, research and education of the labour force. Unlike most other planned economies, production and services are almost exclusively privately owned, often in the form of extended families (guilds) and cooperatives. In key industries and services, the state allocates production through public tenders towards the cheapest suppliers meeting the social, environmental and safety standards set for society as a while.
This make the philosophy and system opposite to free market capitalism, where externalising economic costs and negative side effects for society as a whole are the main ways to lower manufacturing costs, thus being competitive on price alone. In the Mireist system, these costs are internalised in order to avoid that a tax collective would have to balance out for the single-focus approach of profit driven companies. On the other hand, the state does not control the means of production, nor does it own and operate large (basic) industries or even essential services like waterworks or healthcare.
Meritocracy and leadership
The meritocratic nature of traditional Kakuri local government has been translated towards the state and federal level. So Mireism combines a large influence for the individual on lower levels of societal structures and government, but becomes increasingly indirect and meritocratic at higher levels of government. In contrast to other meritocratic and technocratic systems, Mireist leadership is mainly inspirational and a "let them be" style. Leadership provides the necessary tools, information and resources, empowering creativity and self-motivation. Through assessments, financial compensation and continued license to produce or provide, accountability is established. As a result, Mireist leadership is often of a charismatic character, which can lead to negative consequences as well.
Political system
Even though Mireism tries to set itself apart from Socialist and Orderist systems, it is by definition technocratic in nature. While democratic participation is very high at the local level, at the state level the democratic element is so indirect that it becomes autocratic. Allocation of resources is the key task of the government, which most often happens through open tenders. As such, Mireist government has nearly monopolised the license to produce and to a lesser extent the license to provide. The economic system is heavily controlled this way, in order to safeguard social and ecological interests.
Application in Sokoku
Adult members of an extended family have voting rights on all matters of the family, including economic enterprise and the allocation of common (joint) funds. The head of the extended family or guild or a deputy represents the unit's interest in the local territorial government. At this level, all tax payers within the extended family have a right to vote for city or county representatives and budget allocation. This part of societal and government structure shows a lot of parallells with traditional Orkanan government, especially in the Mellanhand tradition.
The political culture of Sokoku is therefore extremely bottom-up, where the emphasis lies on local self determination and cooperative involvement (organizational self management). This is combined with a more meritocratic approach for public office. Local clans, co-ops and extended families elect representatives into local government, where the local executives then elect regional representation. Through these indirect elections, the level of representative democracy becomes less and less the higher up in the hierarchy of public office. There are no political parties actively represented in any office.
The federal parliament forms the legislative. It has 147 members, of which 144 are appointed through indirect elections in districts roughly the same size in population. Parliament works in 12 general committees, one for each executive Secretariat, with 8-16 members each. Parliament is also organised into 12 regional groups, which function as parliamentary factions. Within these groups, information from the committees is shared in order to prepare for upcoming voting procedures. Usually a regional group votes unanimously as one bloc, but this is not a requirement. For the smaller states, there is only one regional group gathering their representation. But large states like Shuuen and Nelyasyat & Ayawantin have more groups, which leads to some sort of political culture between the regional groups. Some are more progressive, some more traditional, but the groups from smaller states are mixed and vote according to regional interests.
Each state appoints one member into the Federal Council (apart from Nelyasyat and Ayatawantin who can appoint two council members) that forms the backbone of the executive cabinet. Each secretary-general is heading a Federal Secretariat, of which there are 16 at the moment.
Society
Collectivism and community cooperation: the role of citizens and government
Human and cultural development:
Education
Economy
According to Chika Mirei there is no real difference between an energy based currency and a fiat based one, since both can be expressed as functions of each others: a certain amount of valuable material can be exchanged for a certain amount of energy, and vice versa, through any rather arbitrary exchange rate. A resulting difference is the definition of wealth in Mireism, which isn't based on economic value but on social ones, more akin welfare. Where Orderism sees societal progress in the form of arts and culture as a symptom of a healthy communal system on an energy based economic system, Mireism sees it the opposite way: that a thriving economy is nothing more than a tool to support social progress, where culture, arts and music are the main expressions of individuals and local communities.
Land ownership comes with a license to use the land for economic purposes like agriculture, forestry or building. However, so-called mobile or hidden assets like streaming water or sub-surface resources are jointly owned. Water management and raw material extraction are public domain and as such contolted completely by the government. While the land owners have the first rights to excavate resources, they are only compensated for the work and possible loss of surface land use. But the revenues of the extracted material are the government's, who allocate it through a tender system.
For example, ercinite ore is extracted against a compensation, then it's allocated to an aluminium manufacturer providing the best price for processing the material within the social and ecological requirements set in the tender. The aluminium is then leased through tenders to manufacturers and end users. Buying an aluminium product gives you the right to use it as intended, but the aluminium itself still is owned by the (federal)cstate. At the end of the life cycle, the product can be returned for a deposit, after which the raw material is allocated a next time. Non-renewable resources can be privately owned, but in practical terms there is a tradition of downcycling where those resources are seen as raw material and not as waste.
Criticism
According to many political scientists, Mireism is more a political system applied in one single nation and not so much a political philosophy or ideology. According to these criticasters, it is only applicable in Sokoku and has no universal value. This is however a minority stance.
Other analysts see Mireism only as a variation of Orderism and not so much an independent ideology. According to them, Mireism is simply post-colonial Orderism with a monetary system instead of energy accounting. Mireism also suffers from the same disadvantages as Orderism, like nepotism in appointments, authoritarian tendencies and economic inefficiency; albeit to a lesser extent.
The implementation of Mireism in Sokoku has led to almost parallel pillars of powers, where each region has its own hierarchy in public office. Instead of a single field of nepotism, it is spread out among the regional pillars through the federal structure of the nation state. However, nine fields of nepotism is a lot less nepotist than the single field of nepotism around in most Orderist systems.